With an election mere days away, today’s release of the non-farm payrolls number and the broader unemployment rate takes on added significance. Understandably, most people will pay attention to the headline numbers and the overall trend. There’s a concept, however, underlying the general employment figures both here and abroad that’s not broadly recognized or understood by the broader public. NAIRU, the “Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment,” in basic terms is the level of “full employment.” Government economists, academics, private sector economists, asset managers, and policymakers have spent a significant amount of time trying to understand true NAIRU levels in countries around the world. Estimation of this metric is difficult, but important; the estimate of NAIRU could have serious implications, for instance, when it comes to the future path of monetary policy and could influence how policymakers approach unemployment issues in developed countries.
Workers who have been unemployed for some time tend to become less attractive to employers. Not only the human capital of the unemployed diminishes over time, but also, as a result of recruitment costs, potential employees are frequently evaluated on the basis of frequency and duration of their periods of unemployment. Job search may also diminish as the unemployed lose contact with the labour market and awareness of job offers. There is indeed empirical evidence that long-term unemployed have a smaller influence on wage bargaining than the short-term unemployed (Guichard and Rusticelli, 2010, Llaudes, 2005 and Elmeskov and MacFarlan, 1993). As a result real wages do not fall sufficiently for the long-term unemployed to be “priced back” into the labour market. Hence increases in the proportion of the long-term unemployed may push up the structural unemployment rate consistent with a stable inflation rate (i.e. the NAIRU).
Other factors, related and unrelated to the above, can influence NAIRU as well. For instance, significant skills mismatches between the labor-force and industry (i.e. businesses across various industries demand skills that the labor force is having a hard time providing) can push NAIRU higher. Demographic factors can affect NAIRU. For instance, the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco identified that NAIRU might rise as the proportion of young workers rises as a percentage of the overall workforce. This is salient now as the Baby Boomer generation retires en masse and younger workers begin to constitute a higher percentage of the force.
NAIRU: US vs Germany
Source: OECD |
What are the current implications for higher NAIRUs? In the US, it means that inflationary pressures could increase at higher levels of unemployment than we were accustomed to pre-crisis. As of right now, there’s still a decent gap between the current unemployment rate of 7.9% and estimated NAIRU just north of 6%. A move in unemployment towards the 6% to 6.5% level might provide an indication to the broader investing public that the Federal Reserve is prepared to move towards a more hawkish and restrictive monetary stance. In Europe, ECB policymakers have a tricky road to navigate; employment gaps are substantial in the peripheral countries such as Spain and Greece, but narrow to nonexistent in countries such as Germany and Finland. Hence, we’ve witnessed serious conflict in the Euro Zone over the future path of monetary policy. Expect the bellyaching to continue. For policymakers in general around the developed world, if we accept the OECD’s notion that higher NAIRUs are tied to higher long-term unemployed, and that high levels of long-term unemployment are tied to structural factors, then it becomes imperative to institute policies that can help bring the long-term unemployed back into the workforce. Perhaps significant job training and similar initiatives could help. Maybe policies shifting current unemployment benefit structures will have an effect to encourage people to reenter the workforce. Some deeper understanding, though, of the carrots and sticks needed to get the long-term unemployed back in productive roles is required of politicians and their advisors. Short-term lurching from problem to problem is insufficient to get these metrics moving back in the right direction.
References/Sources:
Guichard, S. and E. Rusticelli (2011), “Reassessing the NAIRUs after the Crisis”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 918, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kg0kp712f6l-en
Walsh, Carl E. (1998), “The Natural Rate, NAIRU, and Monetary Policy”, FRBSF Economic Letter, 98-28, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. http://www.frbsf.org/econrsrch/wklyltr/wklyltr98/el98-28.html